On Super Tuesday, Democratic voters from Colorado and across the United States will face a serious decision: Sanders or Warren? Biden or Bloomberg? Then, afterward, what kind of wine to drink?
Now, a new study taps into mathematics to âin particular, how hypothetical, and completely rational, individuals might select between two options as they navigate through a noisy social environment.
Say you have a friend who has been a staunch Sanders supporter in the past. Itâs the night before the primary, and they still have not made a decision about who theyâre going to vote for. That suggests that they have received some evidence thatâs in conflict with voting for Sanders."
âZachary Kilpatrick
It turns out that not making a choice can sometimes be as revealing as picking a side, report researchers from the University of Colorado Boulder and the University of Houston. When the people around you are indecisive, for example, that can have a big influence on your own choices.
âSay you have a friend who has been a staunch Sanders supporter in the past,â said Zachary Kilpatrick, a coauthor of the new study and an assistant professor in the at CU Boulder. âItâs the night before the primary, and they still have not made a decision about who theyâre going to vote for. That suggests that they have received some evidence thatâs in conflict with voting for Sanders.â
Kilpatrick will at a meeting of the . (The physical conference has been canceled due to public health concerns).
The groupâs findings, while theoretical, could still inform how we should address real-world problemsâfor example, the spread of misinformation on the internet, he said.
âIf we want to combat the hijacking of our social information networks, we need to understand in a quantitative way how peoplesâ beliefs are swayed by their social connections," Kilpatrick said.
Dreaded decisions
His teamâs research zeroes in on a major question in a field of study called decision-making theory: How people make choices based both on their own, private researchâsuch as watching televised debatesâand through their social interactionsâsay, checking out their friendsâ posts on social media.
Kilpatrick compared that goal to the classic battle of wits between Vizzini and the Dread Pirate Roberts in the 1987 film The Princess Bride. In that scene, the pirate claims to have poisoned one of two glasses of wine. Vizzini, a scofflaw of supposedly vast intellect, must choose the one he thinks is safe to drink.Ěý
It gets complicated.
âWhat Vizzini says is that he knows what the Dread Pirate Roberts knows that he knows,â Kilpatrick said. âBut he takes multiple loops through what we call a âcommon knowledgeâ exchange before he makes the decision on the wine glasses.â
What Vizzini says is that he knows what the Dread Pirate Roberts knows that he knows."
âZachary Kilpatrick
In other words, when you make such an exchange, you need to not only consider what you know about your opponents, but what they know you know about themâand on and on.Ěý
To explore similar kinds of intellectual spirals, Kilpatrick and his colleagues used a series of equations, or mathematical models, to simulate social interactions of varying complexity. Their models didnât revolve around real-life voters, or even pirates, but ârational agentsââtheoretical deciders who always make the right choices based on the evidence available to them.Ěý
The researchers discovered that, when time is of the essence, two fictional voters might go through mental loops akin to Vizziniâs thought process.Ěý
âWeâre both watching the same news show, for example, and I look over to you to see if youâve made a decision or not,â Kilpatrick said. âWe have to account for our common knowledge multiple times until weâve adequately squeezed all of the information that we can out of the fact that you havenât made a decision yet, and I havenât made a decision yet.â
Eventually, it stops. One voter or group of voters in a network might finally receive enough information to feel confident about their choice. And when that happens, other voters might get the impetus they need to quitĚýdithering, too.
The researchers report their findings in a preprint publication online.Ěý
Messy humans
Kilpatrick is quick to note that, of course, no voter is perfectly rational. But scientists can still learn a lot by studying where real-life humans fall in line with what theory suggests they should doâand where they donât.
People should also always try to be aware of the baggage that others in their social networks carry, he added.Ěý
âWhen weâre determining how political leaders or people in our networks make decisions,â Kilpatrick said, âwe should think hard about how Ěýthose individuals are biased in order to figure out what we should take away from their decisions.â
As for your Super Tuesday decision, learn from Vizziniâs example and steer clear of the wine.